Risk Adjusted Efficient Market Return for Stocks
Natasha Pankunni
Research Scholar
School of Management Studies
Cochin University of Science and Technology
Kochi, Kerala, India.
Dr.
S. Rajitha Kumar
Professor
School of Management Studies
Cochin University of Science and Technology
Kochi, Kerala, India.
Abstract
Investment in stocks is
considered to be the most risky among the other investment alternatives. The
risk is due to the uncertainty in the return from stocks. There are various
asset pricing theories in Finance through which investors can estimate the
expected return from investment. One of the most discussed and accepted asset
pricing models is the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) put forward by Sharpe
(1964). Although the model is accepted worldwide, there are wide criticisms
against the model at the same time. One of the significant concept on which the
model is being criticised is the concept of risk free rate of return. It
represents that portion of return to the investors which is availed to them
without taking any risk. It is the minimum and assured return from investment
irrespective of risk. It is the risk premium part of the model that deals with
the return commensurate to the risk taken by the investors. Literature show evidence
that the treasury bills, that are taken as proxy for risk free rate cannot be
completely risk free. Moreover, the concept of risk free rate as the minimum
return from investment, especially from stock investment do not hold logical.
Thus, the authors find a need to treat equity pricing uniquely by substituting
the risk free rate of return with a more appropriate concept. Maintaining the
structural base of CAPM, the minimum return from equity investment should not
be risk free return, but rather the minimum return from equity investment. Such
a minimum return, which is availed to all in an efficient market, can be termed
as ‘Efficient Market Return’. In that case, the total return that an investor
gets from stock will be the risk adjusted efficient market return, the return in
commensurate with the risk he undertakes.
Keywords: Efficient Market Hypothesis, Efficient Market Return, Return, Risk, Risk
Free Rate.
I.
Introduction
Investment
decision has always been a significant task for the investors worldwide. It is
especially true for the case of investors in security market, as it is the most
risky among other investment options. To decide upon stock market investment, investors
do look at the stock prices curiously and inquisitively. Ultimately, their
intention is to earn higher returns over and above their initial investment.
However, it may not always be possible, as the actual return may be less than
what is expected by the investors, the situation that can be precisely ascribed
as risk. Risk is an inherent element in every investment. Under the condition
of uncertainty, investors are concerned about the expected return that they get
from the investment and the means to predict it.
Economists
like Neumann and Morgenstern (1944) came up with models for dealing with asset
choices under the condition of risk. However, those models were normative
models, which had more theoretical value, rather than prescriptive models which
had more pragmatic value. It was then that, Markowitz (1952) formulated a
portfolio selection model, stressing on diversification of investment.
Markowitz explained that through proper diversification of securities, the
unsystematic risk, that is exclusive to individual securities, can be minimised.
Then what remains in the total risk is the systematic risk, which is not
diversifiable. Thus, by reducing the unsystematic risk and thereby the total
risk of portfolio through diversification, portfolio return can be enhanced.
Even though Markowitz pointed out that there existed relation between risk and
return, the nature and depth of the relation was not specified. Here, Sharpe
and others raised question that if there exist relation between risk and
return, then how exactly they were related. The Capital Asset Pricing Model
(CAPM) was developed by Sharpe (1964) as an answer to this question. The CAPM
put forward the concept that the expected return from an asset will be
according to the risk involved in the asset. As per the CAPM, that expected
return from an asset is constituted by the risk free rate (the risk free
return) and a risk premium (return for the additional risk taken). From then,
the model remained a foundation for assessing capital asset prices and for this
vital contribution to the subject Sharpe was awarded with the Nobel Prize in
Economic Sciences in 1990.
However,
the model has been critically evaluated from the very beginning of its
publication. A significant and most discussed part of the model is regarding
its assumption of a risk-free rate of return. Many academicians have criticised
the model on the basis of the risk-free rate of return and its validity. In
this paper, an attempt is made to introduce a new concept of efficient market
return as a valid alternative for the risk-free rate of return in the CAPM, in
pricing equity shares theoretically. The rationale for the same lies in two
facts. The foremost fact is that no investment can be said as risk free,
especially investment in equity. Even the treasury bills rate, which is usually
taken as proxy for risk-free rate cannot be considered as completely risk free.
Another significant fact is that, the CAPM put forwards a general pricing model
for all capital assets, including equity. As equity is the most risky and
common investment, it is appropriate to consider equity pricing separately. In
that case, the concept of risk-free rate of return does not arise at all, as
risk is an inherent and vital element of equity. While investing in equity, one
does not expect risk-free rate of return, but rather expects a minimum rate of
return that is available to all investors in an efficient market. In this paper
an attempt is made to term such minimum rate of return under the efficient
market as the ‘efficient market return’ and introduce as an appropriate
alternative for risk-free rate of return in the CAPM exclusively for pricing
equity.
The
paper is purely conceptual and is organised into five sections. Section I is
the introduction to the paper. Section II covers the review of literature.
Section III explains the methodology, Section IV discusses the concept of
efficient market return and Section V ends with the conclusion of the study.
II.
Review of Literature
From
the development of CAPM by Sharpe (1964) as a model for pricing capital assets
under equilibrium, it has been a topic of debate and discussion across
academicians over nations. Lintner (1965) and Mossin (1966) have contributed
towards the model in support of Sharpe. Sharpe’s intention was to develop a
theory of market equilibrium under the conditions of risk. The significant part
was that there were no attempts from any authors to extend the model of
investor behavior towards building a
market equilibrium theory of asset prices under conditions of risk. For
deriving at the conditions of market equilibrium, two essential assumptions
were made by him. One is that, it was assumed to have a general rate of
interest, namely risk-free rate in the market. It is the rate at which all
investors are assumed to lend and borrow at equal terms. The second assumption
was on homogeneity of investor expectations. The former one form basis for the
model and as per the CAPM, the expected return from an asset equals risk-free
rate of return plus risk premium.
Several
attempts of modifications to the model were also made by various authors
incorporating different aspects. Significant among them includes the work of
Lintner (1969) where returns were calculated in real terms. Thereafter, Brennan
(1970) incorporated the effects of taxation into the model to make it more
realistic in terms. Another salient modification was put forward by Black
(1972) by assuming equilibrium with no risk-free asset. Merton (1973) dealt
with the concern of the investors regarding the future investment opportunities
and proposed an inter-temporal model of capital market. However, Rubenstein
(1974) was keen on a more general class of utility functions. While authors
came up with varying modes of calculating returns, the third moment of return
distributions were considered by Kraus and Litzenberger (1976) in their work.
Ross (1976) introduced an alternative model of Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT)
in between that. Despite the advent of APT, discussions on CAPM continued
actively. The transaction costs were incorporated in the modification made to
the CAPM by Levy (1978). Thereafter, an attempt to incorporate investors’
preference for consumption was made by Breeden (1979). It was market segmentation that was given
importance in the study of Merton (1987). In the version of Markowitz (1990),
the restrictions on short sales were considered. Similarly several modifications
were proposed by various authors.
The
assumption of risk-free rate of return is the significant basis on which the
CAPM has been criticised. One of the significant works based on that was made
by Black (1972). He explored the nature
of capital market equilibrium under two assumptions. First, it was assumed that
there was no riskless asset and that no riskless lending or borrowing was
allowed. Second assumption was that, there was a riskless asset and that only
long positions were allowed in the asset. He found that, under both cases, the
expected return on an asset was a linear function of its beta and that too in a
similar manner when there were no restrictions on borrowing. If there was a
riskless asset, then the slope of line relating expected return on risky asset
to its beta must be smaller than it is when there are no restrictions on
borrowing
The
test of Sharpe-Lintner (S-L) hypothesis is the most commonly used test for
testing the risk-free rate assumption of the CAPM. Friend and Blume (1970),
Black (1972), Black, Jensen and Scholes (1972), Fama and MacBeth (1973) were
among the first few to test the S-L hypothesis. The S-L hypothesis is that the
expected return from any zero-beta security is equal to the risk-free rate of
return. If this hypothesis is rejected, then it means that, the minimum-variance
zero beta portfolio return is the more appropriate measure. In the study of
Black et al. (1972), the hypothesis was rejected as the intercept of Security
Market Line (SML) exceeded the risk-free rate. In the study of Fama and Macbeth
(1973) also, it was pointed out that their data do not support the S-L
hypothesis. Another significant fact to be noted is that, the study was consistent with
the efficient market simultaneously (Fama & MacBeth, 1973). Thus, under efficient market, the
study does not hold the relevance of risk-free rate of return. Another notable
work was by Morgan (1975), who supported Black et al. (1972). He tested the
predictive power of CAPM with minimum-variance zero beta portfolio return
instead of risk-free rate of return. There were no significant difference
between the new model and traditional model and hence he concluded that the new
one will be more appropriate.
Stambaugh
(1982) investigated the sensitivity of the tests of CAPM to portfolios with
various sets of assets returns including bonds, real estate and consumer
durables in addition to stock. As per CAPM, the sensitivity should be
identical. However, the inferences point out significant sensitivity between
the set of assets (Stambaugh, 1982). An attempt for testing the CAPM with
time-varying risks and returns was made by Bodurtha, Jr. and Mark (1991). They
have drawn on Engle's autoregressive conditionally heteroscedastic modeling
strategy to formulate a conditional CAPM with time-varying risk and expected
returns (Bodurtha, Jr., & Mark, 1991). Ho, Strange & Piesse (2000) made another effort whereby they bought
evidence from Hong Kong market for the CAPM anomalies.
Anomalies
regarding risk-free rate of return were investigated across nations. Faff
(2001) tested CAPM based on the evidence from Australia. Brennan and Xia (2001)
observed anomalous returns, from portfolios, relative to the CAPM. Chou and Lin
(2002) tested S-L hypothesis using data from 16 OECD (Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development) countries and Hong Kong. Sun and Yang (2003)
derived a zero beta pricing formula for CAPM with heterogeneous beliefs and was
a generalised model of Black (1972). Avramov and Chordia (2006) tested whether
the CAPM is able to capture the anomalies related to size, value and momentum.
They found that the model failed to capture the anomalies (Avramov
& Chordia, 2006).
Strydom and Charteris (2013) studied the African
risk-free rate anomaly by testing the S-L hypothesis. It was
found that the risk-free proxy yields differed from the minimum return required
by investors in a significant manner. However, the minimum-variance zero-beta
portfolio returns were not different from the minimum required return
significantly.
Over
and above the criticisms on the concept of risk-free rate of return, there were
also criticisms on the proxy selected as risk-free rate. Brennan (1971) pointed
out the difficulty in estimating the risk-free rate as the borrowing and
lending rates differ widely in many nations. He advised to use the zero beta
portfolio return as the minimum required return instead.
Various
academicians and practitioners have accepted the fact that there exist risk
free rate puzzles and asset pricing anomalies. DeJong and Collins (1985) found
that the unexpected changes in the risk free rate influenced the instability of
the equity beta. When there were large unexpected changes in the risk free
rate, the greater were the instability in the beta (DeJong & Collins,
1985). Weil (1989) raised a logical question regarding the risk free rate for
being a much lower rate. In his words, “why the risk free rate is so low, if
agents are so averse to intertemporal substitution?” (Weil, 1989). He
attributes market imperfections and heterogeneity as likely reason for that
puzzle. The risk free rate puzzles are largely observed in shorter periods
(Daniel & Marshall, 1997). Another study noted that the risk free rate
puzzles continued to remain irrespective of sample taken or the nation to which
it belonged (Canova & Nicolo, 2003).
Thus,
there have been wide criticisms against the concept of risk-free rate in the
CAPM and its calculations. It continues to be a relevant problem for further
research and a valid solution for the risk free rate puzzle is always called
for. In this study, an attempt is made to address this issue of risk free rate
puzzle in detail, considering the depth of the problem and the need for a more
appropriate solution. As a solution to the problem, a theoretically derived novel
concept of ‘efficient market return’ is proposed in place of risk free rate of
return in equity pricing.
III.
Methodology
The
paper is conceptual and thus is descriptive in nature. The concept of the
efficient market return and its rationale are explained.
IV.
Concept of Efficient Market Return
As
Fama (2014) had rightly attributed, the two pillars of asset pricing are
efficient capital markets and asset pricing models. He interpreted it as the
Siamese twins of asset pricing (Fama, 2014). Therefore, an asset pricing model
cannot be developed without considering the market efficiency. This paper
attempts to introduce a new concept of ‘Efficient Market Return’ by integrating
the two pillars of asset pricing in a more appropriate way.
A. The
Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)
The
CAPM developed by Sharpe (1964) put forward a model to estimate the expected
return from any capital asset. Markowitz’s (1952) Portfolio theory stated that
through proper diversification, the risk can be reduced and return from
portfolio can be enhanced. The more the diversification, the lesser will be the
unsystematic risk or diversifiable risk. According to Markowitz theory, it is
possible to eliminate the unsystematic risk to a great extent making the
systematic risk the only risk remaining. All assets are prone to systematic
risk, as it cannot be eliminated through diversification. Thus the Portfolio theory
shows that there is a direct relationship between risk and return. It was
Sharpe (1964) who explained the exact relation between risk and return more
accurately. The CAPM states that the return expected from a security is
linearly related with the risk involved in it. The model can be represented as
below:
The
CAPM is shown in the equation (1) in which, E (Ri)
represents the expected return on an asset, βiM is the beta representing the systematic risk
involved in the asset, Rf represents the risk-free rate of return, and ( E
(RM)
- Rf ) is the market premium.
From
the equation (1), it is clear that, when an investor invests in any asset, he
gets two portions of returns. Risk-free rate of return, which is the return
from a risk-free asset that ensures the minimum return for the amount of
investment, constitutes the foremost portion. Usually, the rate of Treasury
bills issued by the government is taken as proxy for the risk-free rate as no
risk is expected from such bills. The second portion of return is the risk
premium. As the name suggests, it is the premium for investors for the
additional risk they had to bear. Therefore, the risk premium will be in
proportion to the risk involved in the asset in which the investment is made.
The risk premium is beta times the market premium. Market premium is the excess
of market return over the risk free rate of return.
Like
any theory, CAPM is based on certain assumptions. Of the assumptions, two
significant assumptions are widely discussed and highlighted. First that the market is efficient and
second that there exist a borrowing and lending at a risk-free rate (Rf), which is the same for all
investors and does not depend on the amount borrowed or lent. These assumptions
are both the strength and weakness of the model.
B. Efficient
Market Hypothesis
The
random nature of price movements of securities was first denoted by Bachelier
(1900) in his study on theory of speculation. After a few years, Kendall (1953)
proposed the theory that stock prices move randomly, through his paper.
The term random walk was more popularised by Fama (1965) through his paper on
the behavior of stock market prices. Then Fama (1970) came up with his most
discussed work on efficient market model. An efficient market is a market where
there is free flow of information and information is available to all
participants. A market is said to be efficient when one cannot make any gain
with his technical savvy over the naive investors who simply buy and hold. In
efficient market when new information reaches, it will be assimilated, then and
there, and reflected in the market price before anyone can take advantage to
make personal gain. The competition between the active participants of the
market lead to such a situation that at any point of time, the market reflects
effects of all past information and also expected future events. In such a
market, the price of securities will be an unbiased estimate of its intrinsic
value. It may sometimes vary leading to situation of undervaluation and
overvaluation, but those anomalies will not last due to the process of
arbitrage.
Fama
(1970) postulates three forms of market efficiency namely weak-form market
efficiency, semi-strong form market efficiency and strong-form market
efficiency. Weak form efficient market is a market where the security prices
reflect all past prices and semi-strong form efficient market is the market
where all public information is reflected in the prices. Under strong-form
efficient market, the prices reflect all public as well as private information.
Thus,
it is to be noted that, under efficient market, investors will be availed with
a return common to all. No one can gain over another with any new information
or technical expertise, as the information is available to all alike. But, that
is not the case with all investors who invest in stocks. Some investor do gain
more returns than the others. There are two possible reasons for that. The
first reason can be the availability of new information to those particular
investors alone. The second reason can be their decision to invest in more
risky securities than others. The first case is not possible in an efficient
market. It means that the additional return that the investors gain over the
others is because of the additional risk that they bear.
C. No
Investment is Risk-free
An
important assumption of the CAPM is that there exists a risk-free rate at which
borrowing and lending is done. The risk-free rate of return forms the basis for
estimation of return from investment in any capital asset. It is the minimum
return that one gets when investing in capital assets, as it is the return from
risk-free asset. The risk-free asset is the last potential or viable investment
opportunity when the assets are listed based on the risk involved. Van Horne
(1970) stated that short term treasury bills rates could be approximated to
short term risk free rate. He also pointed out that this short term risk free
rate can be used as a basis for structuring long term risk free rate (Van
Horne, 1970). So, the logic behind the model for establishing risk-free return
as the basic return is that, an investor will be assured of at least the
risk-free return, as all other assets have risk higher than the risk-free
asset.
Here,
a question arises: Is investment risk-free? It is an accepted fact that risk is
inherent in every investment, only the intensity varies. The treasury bills
issued by governments, which are taken as risk-free rate proxy, are definitely
least risky, but not cent percent risk-free. It is true that the government
securities are more or less free from credit risk, but they are prone to
interest rate risk and inflation risk sometimes. It is a fact that, when a
rupee is invested today and return is expected tomorrow, there is implied risk.
Thus, when government comes under threat, it is possible that the government
securities can also come under threat. As far as government securities continue
as investment options, risk cannot be said to be completely eliminated. DeJong
and Collins (1985) showed that the risk free rate is prone to unexpected
changes, which in turn lead to beta instability. For the same reason, such
securities cannot be called as “risk-free” in true sense. They may be suitably
termed as least risky or risk-less, rather than risk-free.
Another
vital point to be considered here is regarding the lack of clarity in the usage
of the risk free rate for varying time horizons. Mukherji (2011) had pointed
out the usual flaw among the academicians, where they use either short term or
long term treasury bills rate as risk free rate, without having a proper
reason. He stressed the fact that there lacked an empirical justification for
selecting the risk free rates. Moreover, the treasury securities are prone to
inflation risk through the time horizon (Mukherji, 2011).
Bruner
et al. (1998) showed that there was wide choice for the risk free rate. He
states that 70% of corporations and financial advisors used treasury bonds of
ten years or more maturity, while only less than 10% used treasury bills
(Bruner, Eades, Harris, & Higgins, 1998). Thus, there exists apprehension
in the concept of risk free rate, its calculation and relevance.
Another
point that is to be highlighted is that, equity investment is considered as the
most risky investment among other alternatives. In equity investment, there is
no relevance for the concept of risk-free rate of return. It is true that
risk-free rate of return gives the minimum return from any investment as is
envisaged in the CAPM. As CAPM is a pricing model for all capital assets, the
model may calculate the expected return from equity as a whole in a generic
manner. However, conceptually, when equity investment is specifically
treated, risk-free rate of return estimation is irrelevant and inappropriate.
Under an efficient market concept, when one invests in equity, what is expected
is a minimum return common to all investors of equity in an efficient market.
One will not expect the ‘risk-free rate of return’ as return from equity
investment. Therefore, in calculating the expected rate of equity return, it is
not conceptually and logically sound to estimate the risk-free rate of return,
which is neither related nor relevant to equity. That means, a more appropriate
method for pricing equity exclusively, is called for. A unique model for equity
pricing is quite relevant in the realm of finance.
D. Efficient
Market Return as an Alternative for Risk-Free Rate of Return
Even
though CAPM is criticised on various grounds, it is a fact that the framework
that the model provide is inevitable for asset pricing. Authors like Black
(1972) are of opinion that a rational market essentially needs CAPM. As Fama
and French states, “The CAPM is wanted, dead or alive” (Fama
& French, 1996). Hansen and Richard
(1987) found that the static version of CAPM was a failure. He recommended a
dynamic version of CAPM as a valid one (Hansen & Richard, 1987).
At
the same, substituting risk free rate with more appropriate concepts, have been
also tried by various academicians. Black (1972) recommended substituting the
risk free rate return in the CAPM with the rate of return on portfolio of
stocks with zero-beta. The model was called two factor model (Black, 1972).
The
fundamental concept of CAPM is that, when one invests in an asset, he can
expect a minimum rate of return for his invested amount and an additional rate
of return for the quantum of additional risk taken by the investor. The
rationale of using treasury bills rate as risk-free rate representing minimum
rate of return in the CAPM is that, it is the least risky among the other investment
alternatives. That is the case of CAPM, the generic model for capital asset
pricing.
Being
realised the relevance of pricing equity exclusively, an equity pricing model
which gives the expected return from equity as a sum of minimum return from
equity and a risk premium, would be appropriate. In case of such a unique model
for equity pricing, instead of risk-free return, the minimum expected return should
be the return that is available to all investors in the market, which is
assumed to be efficient. This minimum return from efficient market can be
termed as “efficient market return”.
Efficient
market return is the return available to the investors in the efficient market
regardless of risk. It is the minimum return that an investor gets when invest
in stock under efficient market. Whether the investor is naive or one with
technical expertise or one having insider knowledge, there is only one and
single return for identical amount of investment under state environment, that
will be available to all, which can be rightly referred to as efficient market
return. Any return that is excess over this return can be attributed to the
additional risk that the investor take alone. Thus, the minimum return from
equity investment, irrespective of the risk, is the efficient market return and
it will be more appropriate than risk-free rate of return while pricing equity.
E. Risk
Adjusted Efficient Market Return
Given
the efficient market return as minimum return, the total return that an
investor will get from investment in stock will be the efficient market return
after adjusting the corresponding risk taken by the investors. The return will
be thus commensurate with the risk undertaken by the investor. Thus, what an
investor gets from investing in stocks will be the ‘Risk Adjusted Efficient
Market Return’.
V.
Conclusion
The
CAPM developed by Sharpe (1964) is the fundamental model for pricing capital
assets. However, the concept of risk-free rate of return along with its
estimation and implications in the model were criticised by academicians since
then. It is assumed that risk-free rate of return is the minimum return one can
expect from any investment. It is also assumed that the market is efficient.
So, when equity investment is exclusively taken, the concept of risk-free rate
as minimum rate of return does not hold, as the equity is the most risky
investment. Through this paper, the authors put forward a more appropriate
concept of efficient market return as an alternative for risk-free rate of
return in pricing equity. Efficient market return is the return available to
all investors under an efficient market environment irrespective of the risk
undertaken. It will be the minimum rate of return that an investor gets from an
equity investment, rather than risk-free rate of return. Thus, the efficient market
return will be a more appropriate concept while pricing equity than risk-free
rate of return.
References
Avramov, D.,
& Chordia, T. (2006). Asset Pricing Models and Financial Market Anomalies. The
Review of Financial Studies, 19(3), 1001-1040.
Bachelier,
L. (1900). In L. Bachelier, Theory of Speculation (pp. 21-86). Ecole
Normale Superieure.
Black,
F. (1972). Capital Market Equilibrium with Restricted Borrowing. The Journal
of Business, 444-455.
Bodurtha,
J. N., Jr., & Mark, N. C. (1991). Testing the CAPM with Time-Varying Risks
and Returns. The Journal of Finance, 1485-1505.
Breeden,
D. (1979). An Intertemporal Asset Pricing Model with Stochastic Consumption and
Investment Opportunities . Journal of Financial Economics, 265 -296.
Brennan,
M. (1970). Taxes, Market Valuation and Corporate Financial Policy. National
Tax Journal, 417-427.
Brennan,
M. J., & Xia, Y. (2001). Assessing Asset Pricing Anomalies. The Review
of Financial Studies, 14(4), 905-942.
Bruner,
R. F., Eades, K. M., Harris, R. S., & Higgins, a. C. (1998). Best Practices
in Estimating the Cost of Capital: Survey and synthesis. Financial Practice
and Education, 8, 13-28.
Canova,
F., & Nicolo, G. D. (2003). The Properties of the Equity Premium and the
Risk-Free Rate: An Investigation Across Time and Countries. IMF Staff
Papers, 50(2), 222-249.
Daniel,
K., & Marshall, D. (1997). Equity-Premium and Risk-Free-Rate Puzzles At
Long Horizons. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 1, 452–484.
DeJong,
D. V., & Collins, D. W. (1985). Explanations for the Instability of Equity
Beta: Risk-Free Rate Changes and Leverage Effects. The Journal of Financial
and Quantitative Analysis, 20(1), 73-94.
Fama,
E. F. (1965). The Behavior of Stock-Market Prices. The Journal of Business,
34-105.
Fama,
E. F. (1970). Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work.
Journal of Finance, 383-417.
Fama,
E. F. (2014). Two Pillars of Asset Pricing. The American Economic Review,
104(6), 1467-1485.
Fama,
E. F., & French, K. R. (1996). The CAPM is Wanted, Dead or Alive. The
Journal of Finance, 51(5), 1947-1958.
Fama,
E. F., & MacBeth, J. D. (1973). Risk, Return, and Equilibrium: Empirical
Tests. The Journal of Political Economy, 607-636.
Hansen,
L., & Richard, S. F. (1987). The Role of Conditioning Information in
Deducing Testable Restrictions Implied by Dynamic Asset Pricing Models. Econometrica,
55, 587-613.
Kraus,
A., & Litzenberger, R. (1976). Skewness Preference and the Valuation of
Risk Assets. Journal of Finance, 1085-1100.
Levy,
H. (1978). Equilibrium in an Imperfect Market: A Constraint on the Number of
Securities in a Portfolio. American Economic Review, 643 - 658.
Lintner.
(1965). The valuation of risky assets and the selection of stock portfolios and
capital budgets. Review Econ. Statist., 13-37.
Lintner,
J. (1969). The Aggregation of Investors’ Diverse Judgements and Preferences. Journal
of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 346-382.
Markowitz,
H. (1952). Portfolio Selection. The Journal of Finance, 77-91.
Merton,
R. (1973). An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model. Econometrica,
867-887.
Merton,
R. (1987). A Simple Model of Capital Market Equilibrium With Incomplete
Information. Journal of Finance, 483-510.
Mukherji,
S. (2011). THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL’S RISK-FREE RATE. The
International Journal of Business and Finance Research, 5(2), 75-83.
Neumann,
J. v., & Morgenstern, O. (1944). Theory of Games and Economic Behavior.
Princeton, NJ.: Princeton University Press.
Ross,
S. (1976). Arbitrage Theory of Capital Asset Pricing. Journal of Economic
Theory, 341-360.
Rubinstein,
M. (1974). An Aggregation Theorem for Securities Markets. Journal of
Financial Economics, 225 - 244.
Sharpe,
W. F. (1964). Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under
Conditions of Risk. The Journal of Finance, 425-442.
Stambaugh,
R. F. (1982). On the exclusion of assets from tests of the two-parameter model:
A sensitivity analysis. J. Finan. Econ. 10, 237-268.
Van
Horne, J. C. (1970). The Function and Analysis of Capital Market Rates.
New Jersey: Prentice-Hall Inc.
Weil,
P. (1989). The Euity Premium Puzzle and The Risk-Free Rate Puzzle. Journal
of Monetary Economics, 24, 401-421.